Evaluating Projects under
U ncerta inty
March 17, 2004
3/17/04
Nuclear Energy Economics and
Policy Analysis
1
• Project risk = possible variation in cash flow s
3/17/04
Nuclear Energy Economics and
Policy Analysis
2
Commonly used measure of project risk is the variability of the return
3/17/04
Nuclear Energy Economics and
Policy Analysis
3
M ethods of dealing w ith
uncertainty in project evaluations
• Sensitivity analysis
• Risk adjusted MARR
• Probability trees
• Monte Carlo simulations
3/17/04
Nuclear Energy Economics and
Policy Analysis
4
Exampl e showin g ho w us e o f ‘ risk-adjusted ’ MARR s can
lea d t o th e wron g decision (from Sullivan et al, Engineering Economy , (11th ed), p. 445)
The Atlas Corporation is considering two alternatives, both affected by uncertainty to different degrees, for increasing the recovery of a precious metal from its smelting process. The firm’s MARR f or its ri sk-free investments is 10% per year.
Alternative
End-of-year, k
P
Q
Because of te chnical considerations, Alternative P is thought to be m or e uncertain than
Alternative Q. Therefore, according to the Atlas Corporation’s “Engineering Economy Handbook”, the risk-adjusted MARR applied to P will be 20% per year and the risk-adjusted MARR f or Q has been set at 17% per year. Which alternative should be recommended?
3/17/04
Nuclear Energy Economics and
Policy Analysis
5
0 |
-160,000 |
-160,000 |
1 |
120,000 |
20,827 |
2 |
60,000 |
60,000 |
3 |
0 |
120,000 |
4 |
60,000 |
60,000 |
Solution
At the risk-free MARR, bot h alternative s hav e th e s am e PW of $39, 659. What to do?
All else equal, choose Q, because it is less uncertain (hence less riskier) than P.
But now, do a PW analysis, using Atlas Corporation’s prescribed ri sk-adjusted MARRs for the two options:
PW P = -160 ,000 + 120,000 (P/F, 20%, 1) + 60,000 (P/F , 20%, 2) + 60,000 (P/ F, 20% , 4)
= $ 10,602
PW Q = -160 ,000 + 20,827 (P/F,17%,1) + 60,000 (P/F,17%, 2) + 120,000 (P/F,17%,3) +
+ 60,000 (P/F,17%, 4)
= $ 8575
Hence according to this method we would choose P. In other words, using the risk-adjusted MARRs makes the more uncertain project, P, look MORE attractive than Q!!
3/17/04
Nuclear Energy Economics and
Policy Analysis
6
Example of probabilistic analysis
Consider th e simple decision whether to make a new investment, when there is uncertainty about the duration of demand.
I 0 = 6800
R = 7000/yr
M = 2000 + (n-1)1000 i = 20%
The probability of demand fo r the service provided by this asset persisting for:
Question: Should this investment be made?
3/17/04
Nuclear Energy Economics and
Policy Analysis
8
Solution (contd.)
From Sullivan et al, p.447
3/17/04
Nuclear Energy Economics and
Policy Analysis
7
N |
I N |
1 |
1600 |
2 |
800 |
3 |
400 |
4 |
200 |
1yr |
0.1 |
2yr |
0.2 |
3yr |
0.3 |
4yr |
0.4 |
Example (continued)
Question: Should this investment be made?
LAC I o ( A / P ,20%, N ) I N ( A / F ,20 %, N ) 2000 1000 ( A / G , 20 %, N )
1yr p =0.1 PW = -2132 px PW = -213.2
2yr p =0.2 PW=-828 p x PW = -166
Yes
3yr p =0.3 PW = 6 p x PW = 2
Expected Value
= -$236
4 yr p = 0.4 PW = 352 p x P W = 141
No
0
3/17/04
Nuclear Energy Economics and
Policy Analysis
9
N |
LAC |
Levelized OI |
(P/A,20%,N) |
P W o f O.I. |
Probability |
1 |
-9560 |
-2360 |
0.833 |
-2132 |
0.1 |
2 |
-7542 |
-542 |
1.528 |
-828 |
0.2 |
3 |
-6997 |
3 |
2.106 |
6 |
0.3 |
4 |
-6864 |
136 |
2.589 |
352 |
0.4 |
The Problem of Investment Timing
Exampl e 1 : Uncertaint y ove r Prices Widget factory
Initial cost = I = $1600 Annual operating cost = 0
Production rate = 1 widget per year Current widget p rice = $200
Price next year (and forever after):
$300 with probability 0.5
$100 with probability 0.5
t =0
t =1
t =2
0.5
P 1 = $300
P 2 = $300
P o = $200
0.5
P 1 = $100
P 2 = 100
Assume interest rate of 10%/yr
Question : Should the f irm invest now, or should it w ait for 1 year and see whether the price of widgets goes up or down?
3/17/04
Nuclear Energy Economics and
Policy Analysis
10
Example 1 (contd.)
Since expected price of widgets is always $200, th e NPV of an investment now is
NPV 1600
0
200
( 1 0 . 1 )
t
1600 2200 $600
Thus it might seem sensible to go ahead.
But what if we wait until next year? Then we would decide to invest only if the price goes up. If the price falls, i t would make no sense to invest.
The NPV i n this case is given by:
1600
NPV (0.5 )
1.1 ( 1 0. 1 )
t 1
300 ˘ 1600 3300 ˘ 850
t
0.5 $ 773
1 . 1 1.1 1 . 1
So if we wait a year before de ciding whether to invest in the factory, the project NPV today is $773. Clearl y i t i s bette r t o wai t tha n t o inves t righ t away .
If we had n o choice, and either ha d to invest now or never, we would obviously choose to invest, since this would have a positive NPV of $600. But the flexibility to choose to postpone the de cision and invest next year if the market price is right is w orth something. Specifically, it is worth 77 3-600 = $173.
In other words, we should be willing to p ay up to $173 more for an investment o pportunity that is flexible than one that only allows us the choice of investing now or never. This is the value of flexibility in this case.
Still another way of saying this is that there is an opportunit y cost of investing now, rather than waiting.
3/17/04
Nuclear Energy Economics and
Policy Analysis
11
Example 2 -- Uncertainty over costs
We can consider two different kinds of cost uncertainty
a. Suppose that I = $1600 today, but th at next year it will increase to $2400 or decrease to $800, each with a probability of 0.5. ( The cause of this uncertainty could be stochastic fluctuations in input prices, or regulatory uncertainties.) The interest rate is again 10% per year
Question: Should we invest today or wait to decide until next year? As before, if we invest today the NPV is given by:
NPV 1600
0
200
( 1 0 . 1 )
t
1600 2200 $600
If we wait until next year, it will be sensible to invest only if the investment cost falls to
$800, which happens with a probability of 0.5. In th is case the NPV is given by:
NPV (0.5 )
80 0 200 ˘ 800 2200 ˘
( 1 0. 1 ) ( 1 0 . 1 )
t 1
t
0.5 $636
1.1 1.1
so once again i t is better to wait than to invest immediately.
3/17/04
Nuclear Energy Economics and
Policy Analysis
12
Example 2 -- contd.
a. Suppose, alternatively, that there are uncertainties over how much it is going to cost to com plete the project that can only be resolved by actually doing it. You don’t know for certain how much it is going to cost until you complete it. Let’s say that th is uncertainty takes the following form: To build the widget fa ctory you first have to spend $1000, and that there is a 50% probability that the f actory will then be complete, and a 50% probability that you will have to spend another $3000 to complete it. Assume that the widget price remains constant at $200, an d that the interest rate is 10%.
At first blush, the investment would make no sense. The expected cost of the factory is: 1000 + 0.5.(3000) = 2500.
200
And since the value of the factory =
t 0
1.1
t
2200
, we might conclude that it makes no
sense to proceed. But this ignores the add itional information that is generated b y completing the f irst phase of the project, and that we can choose to abandon t he pr oject if completion requires an extra $3000. The true NPV is:
NPV 1000 (0 . 5 ) 1 . 1 t $ 100
200
t 0
Since the NPV is positive, one should invest in the first stage of the project.
3/17/04
Nuclear Energy Economics and
Policy Analysis
13